See no evil … (Restructuring is coming)

My house had a problem with pigeons nesting in the chimney. Sometimes we’d come home to find one sitting on the couch. On one such occasion I could hear the bird in the chimney. To keep it from coming into the living room (and having to deal with its mess), I decided the easiest thing was to barricade the fireplace with flattened cardboard. I assumed it would eventually go back where it came from.

My decision to ‘see no evil’ is not uncommon. It’s what a lot of people do with problems whose solutions are inconvenient. Thinking about this helped me to understand how perfectly sensible policymakers and opinion-shapers can coalesce around nonsensical policy. I still have Greece in mind. It was far easier for the EU policy establishment to wish the problem away than address its core. Perhaps they thought that the problem would solve itself if they applied a tough enough lid. What else to compare the 110 billion euro package of financing but a lid to cover an intractable problem? All of the adjustment was placed upon the debtor; none on the creditor.

What I did not know about the pigeon, and did not inquire to check, was that it was unable to fly back up the chimney. I had sentenced it to bloody its wings to the point of exhaustion. As days passed without the bird’s escape, I had to consider that the box was no solution at all. The problem would not fix itself. By that time it was too late. I took the box away and helped the creature outside through the front door. Its wings were so badly damaged that it couldn’t fly. It crawled beneath a bush and I think there it demised.

Will the EU realistically face its inconvenient problem before the worst damage is done? Some signs are hopeful. The EU’s Economy Commissioner Olli Rehn yesterday said that the a majority of the 440 billion euro support scheme for Greece, Spain, Portugal sovereign finance can be converted into a European TARP (this is the “European Financial Stability Facility”, which is worth potentially 750 billion euros when IMF contributions and additional support using the EU budget as collateral are added). Not pro-actively, but in the event that domestic banks are found wanting as a result of stress tests that will now include a sovereign debt “shock”. How big of a shock should those tests apply? One answer comes from John Dizard, who on July 4 highlighted the extent to which quasi-sovereign Greek debt is already being restructured (h/t Naked Capitalism). According to this June 9 press release (pdf), the Greek Ministry of Finance is offering to assume several tranches of outstanding hospital debts in exchange for zero-coupon securities, for an overall haircut estimated at 19%. (Dizard quotes a London emerging-market bond dealer who scoffs at that discount; he thinks the market would buy such debt at 70% discount.)

Greece is a microcosm. We live in a world where the creditor-debtor relationship will not be resolved as expected at the time when the debt was contracted. Putting a lid on the problem — even a very expensive lid with pledges of ‘shock and awe’ support — is not going to solve it. Does Greece need to reform? Absolutely. Can reforms alone bring its economy back to a sustainable growth path? Absolutely not. Creditor adjustment is around the corner. If Rehn’s latest statements mean that the European banking system will be treated to capital support from the ‘Financial Stability Facility’ as a consequence of some relief for the debtor (whether friendly or otherwise), that is fantastic. After a financial crisis, the economy’s external position must flip over. Where once it ran big current account deficits it now must run big surpluses. One step toward doing so is relief in the form of lower servicing on outstanding debt. Just look at Argentina’s current account items post-2001 and you’ll see how dramatically this contributed to the economy’s financial surplus.

It is true too that we live in a world with vast underemployed resources. The way forward is debt restructuring: some mixture of relief for the borrower and recapitalisation for the creditor, which recapitalisation is financed by the manufacture of new money. Yes! Austrian-school adherents might not like it, but that doesn’t matter. If the monetary authority does not create this money, the assured consequence is deflation. 1/ How can it create new money? It needs to mark distressed assets on its balance sheets as ‘fudge’: neither money-good nor written off. If the central bank has to write down bad assets, the loss comes out of its capital. Since central banks operate on a thin capital cushion, the finance ministry has to provide the additional capital. The extreme paranoia over fiscal accounts makes this politically difficult. Hence: don’t write down the debt, but don’t expect its repayment either. The end result is that illiquid assets in the economy are replaced with perfectly liquid assets — central bank money, which is ‘outside money’ so long as the illiquid assets acquired by the central bank are no longer treated de facto as anyone’s liability.

This is already happening at the world’s largest central banks. But it needs to be ramped up dramatically. Over the howling protestation of Austrian-school acolytes. An accurate grip on the nature of money is crucial to devising the proper policy path. Money is a means of exchange. That’s it. Finis. Forget about being a store of value, a unit of account, etc. Yes, it is those things, but they pale in significance compared to the means-of-exchange role of money. 2/ There is no sense in which a puritanical view is appropriate for money. Money must be supplied to the point of calling into employment the productive capacity of the economy. This essential insight has been re-discovered time and again, always at the point of greatest financial distress. If you are the slightest interested in this, have a look at Jacob Viner’s 1939 Studies in the Theory of International Trade, which reviews the rich debate over the nature of money during the decades of inconvertibility of British sterling into gold during the Napoleonic Wars (but keep in mind that despite Viner’s otherwise fulsome support for what we would call a ‘fiat money’ position he somehow comes down on the side of Ricardo and the need for a gold foundation of money, an anomaly which I put down to the overwhelming dogma of the interwar years in which Viner wrote — namely, the view that gold was the proper basis for money, which did not abate when convertibility was suspended generally around 1931, on which topic is my entire phd thesis).

Obviously, Argentina’s path post-2001 cannot be travelled by everyone simultaneously; there cannot be a net global current account surplus. From where will come the deficits? This is where my view turns the most gloomy. Those in the best position on a net international investment position basis are those which must take up the burden. (If consuming in excess of production can be considered a burden.) And yet we see Germany embracing “tough” austerity measures, in the notion that it must set an example for peers.  It needs to do exactly the opposite. And what about China? I cannot say at present; I need the time to look into the situation much more deeply, and I don’t have it. But in the end, countries like China and Germany must be cautious about what they wish for. The US economy cannot be the consumer of last resort in this era. And yet it cannot take control of its exchange rate because it is the global numeraire. Hence I see few options except a unilateral universal import surcharge akin to Nixon’s 10% surcharge accompanying the dollar devaluation in August 1971. 3/ After all: who has benefited the most from globalization over the last decade or two? US households have clearly enjoyed some nice goodies (financed by debt), but Chinese households have emerged from poverty on a scale never before witnessed (over three decades). And I would urge caution on those who are tempted to think the US “can’t make anything”. Times will be austere, it can make a lot of what it needs, you just wait.

1/ I’m constantly having to restate this, but it’s worthwhile. Deflation is not ‘OK’. If you’re of a financially puritanical mindset, as are the Austrian school adherents, then you probably see deflation as no worse than inflation, or a perfectly reasonable payback for the excesses tolerated during the prior boom. What this view ignores is the real-world problem of nominally contracted debt. When prices are falling, your income probably does too (and for sure if you are a vendor!). But what about your obligations — do they fall with the price level? Usually not. And that’s the problem.

2/ Some of my views have matured since writing this 2008 essay on gold’s enduring allure. Regarding the exchange function of money: this is the reason for inevitable emissions of quasi-monies in severe financial contractions; people need a medium of exchange. If they cannot come into receipt of the “ideal unit” (as Nussbaum called it) then they will try something else. Community vouchers are already much in evidence in the United States and I would bet on seeing a lot more of them.

3/ Ever wondered how the OECD world came round to floating their currency regimes? One factor was this import surcharge. The world’s key creditor economies at that point, eg Japan and Germany, were also steadfast peggers to the dollar, even after Nixon’s August devaluation. But that, combined with the import surcharge, proved too much, and they had to let go. Also helpful, of course, was an intellectual climate for the first time strongly in support of floating exchange rates.

Sobering thoughts about the price level

Money’s key function is means of exchange (beats bartering). Most money is created by the financial system. When it creates a loan, ‘new’ money is created. (A new entry is created in the asset ledger of the financial institution, which is the loan that you need to repay. A similar entry is created on the liability side. This is the money, drawn against the financial institution, that you are enabled to spend. Because of fractional-reserve banking, this is ‘new’ money, it doesn’t come from the financial institution’s existing money holdings e.g. deposits.) OK. Now run that process in reverse. In other words, the balance sheet of the financial institution shrinks, i.e. there is net loan repayment, whether because people are trying to reduce their debts or because the financial institution itself needs for prudential or regulatory reasons to increase its capital/asset ratio. Money is destroyed.
All else being equal, this would be deflationary. Why hasn’t it been? Many people are tempted to look at the foundational component of money in the economy, which is ‘base money’, ‘central bank money’, ‘high-powered money’, m0, they’re all synonyms. This is the money created by the Fed. And yes the Fed has created legions of this money in the wake of the aforementioned financial institution balance sheet shrinkage a.k.a. de-leveraging. But this has not been effective (at least so far — that expansion of m0 is a huge source of worry for some). There is no appetite to ‘pyramid’ new money (loans) on top of this base money, resulting in this money just accumulating in the banks’ own balances. To see this, it is imperative to look at measures of money supply which include such bank-created money.
So why no deflation? The reason is that government spending has created new money. The financial system writes it the loans and thus the new spending power, which is injected into the economy. Fiscal deficits have propped up the price level. Which brings me to the “sobering thoughts”. If this process is now likely to go into reverse or at least to abate, it is hard to believe that the price level will not fall. This may be an ideologically gleeful outcome for some people, i.e. those of the Austrian school, but do not be fooled. Deflation in the presence of nominally contracted debt is a nightmare scenario. And no person of the pro-deflation school has yet been able to explain away that particular dilemma.

“Predictions of a Bond Market Bubble are Wrong”

If you can access it, be sure to read Predictions of a Bond Market Bubble are Wrong, by David Rosenberg writing in today’s FT. It clarifies much confusion about the inflation/deflation outlook and is consistent with the periodic emphasis here on the irrational fears of inflation in the midst of a global surfeit of productive capacity. Which fears were rampant at the depths of the Great Depression.

Message to new visitors to this site, June-July 2010

I am by training and background a professional economist. In 2005 I began writing a dissertation on the international monetary dimensions of the Great Depression. As recently as 2009 I was downplaying the notion that my studies had much to say about the current business cycle. Today, however, we are seeing a policy approach that is disturbingly familiar from the Great Depression.  

Excerpt from the Italian economists’ joint letter

We believe … that the present direction of economic policy may soon prove to be unsustainable. If the conditions do not exist for the realisation of a development plan based on the objectives outlined, there will be an extemely high risk of debt-driven deflation and the consequent disintegration of the euro zone. This is because some countries could be sucked into a vicious spiral, caused by short-sighted national “austerity” policies and the resulting pressure of speculation. At a certain point these countries could be forced out of the monetary union or could deliberately decide to leave it in order to try to create their own economic policies in defence of internal markets, incomes and employment. If things actually went in that direction, it is obvious they would not necessarily be seen as the main culprits for the crisis of the European union.


(Emphasis in the original. Full text at the official website. )

Skidelsky (Keynes’s biographer) on today’s re-hearsing of 1931

Abridged by Brad de Long.
(Politicians) talk about the need to restore “confidence in the markets”. The argument here is that deficits do positive harm by destroying business confidence… fear of higher taxes, fear of default, fear of inflation…. The parallel with what happened in 1931 is irresistible. In February of that year, Philip Snowden, the Labour government’s chancellor of the exchequer, set up the May Committee to recommend cuts in public spending. The committee projected a budget deficit of £120m, later raised to £170m, the latter figure amounting to about 5 per cent of gross domestic product, and proposed raising taxes and reducing spending to “balance the budget”…. Keynes was one of the very few who stood out against the herd…. When the Conservative-Liberal coalition that had succeeded the Labour government introduced an emergency budget in September 1931, Keynes again stood out against the chorus of approval. The budget was, he wrote, “replete with folly and injustice”. He explained to an American correspondent that “every person in this country of super-asinine propensities, everyone who hates social progress and loves deflation, feels that his hour has come and triumphantly announces how, by refraining from every form of economic activity, we can all become prosperous again.”
Scott here. Just to re-cap the international monetary parallels, explained in greater depth elsewhere in this blog:
  • In 1931, governments were urged (typically by financial elites / creditors generally / the governments’ creditors specifically) to stick to the current monetary arrangements at all costs. The need to do so was framed sometimes in morals and frequently in histrionics.
  • A parallel today is the EU’s approach to weaker eurozone members like Greece; it wants them to stay within the euro and to honour all debts and somehow to manage this through a feat of growth-via-austerity.
  • The parallel is even closer now that the eurozone’s biggest creditor (Germany) has kicked off an austerity campaign of its own, just as the rest of the continent needs it to start becoming a net importer. (France was the biggest European creditor in 1931 and it too embarked on an austerity drive.)
  • Scared by the travails of Greece (and soon Spain), governments beyond the eurozone are jumping on the austerity bandwagon — just as their neighbours need them to do the opposite.
  • To anticipate some counter-points: I can understand the importance of repaying the creditor, but the situation is now beyond that possibility. Once that fact is recognized, the key is to ask what approach will be best. (My suggestions are all over this blog.)
  • The tragedy of 1931 is that forcing debtors into a straitjacket only makes them adopt illiberal means. This is precisely the way to understand the resort of central European debtor economies to exchange controls and ultimately to the draconian ‘clearing arrangements’ as the exchange controls became too porous.

Moody’s cuts Greece; “We’re not nearly as gloomy as others in the market”

Moody’s today cut Greece sovereign debt to ‘junk’ status, citing threats to growth.

“If they still need to take additional measures to reduce the debt because of slow growth, that would be a difficult political decision … because obviously that entails still more sacrifice on the part of the population,” Moody’s told Reuters. 
And that’s the whole point about the current approach: No growth. The market cares about debt in relation to GDP. If the denominator is falling, you’re making no progress. Krugman and Kevin O’Rourke make the point very cogently. 
Moody’s also told Reuters: “We’re not nearly as gloomy as others in the market.”